Author Helen DeWitt has moved into an apartment with no phone and no Internet connection for 5
months so she can get some work done. [link]
I have not.
That's why I am reading about Helen DeWitt instead of getting some work done.
Author Helen DeWitt has moved into an apartment with no phone and no Internet connection for 5
months so she can get some work done. [link]
I have not.
That's why I am reading about Helen DeWitt instead of getting some work done.
although the tail is very interesting and we enable it, the vast majority of the revenue remains in the head. And this a lesson that businesses have to learn. While you can have a long tail strategy, you better have a head, because that’s where all the revenue is.
and this prompts Long Tail author Chris Anderson to make several admissions:
But there were clearly exceptions to [Long Tail behaviour]. One of the main ones was the irony that there was a very short Head of Long Tail aggregators: Amazon, iTunes, Google and their kin dominate their markets to a blockbuster-like degree.
I blamed this on a still-young market and assumed that even aggregators would fall victim to the flight from one-size-fits-all someday. But new research from McKinsey (free registration req'd) suggests that this sort of radical inequality is increasingly the norm as markets get more networked.
"Powerlaws do imply wildly unequal distributions of money, power, celebrity and everything else." – so much for 'democratization'.
And it's not just companies. The Long Tail–the powerlaw created by network effects–may be creating super-celebrity, too.
As I've said many times, both in the book and elsewhere, most of the rewards in the Tail are non-monetary: a larger audience for producers, and more choice for consumers.
I'll end by conceding a point: It's hard to make money in the Tail.
There's more, and he holds on to some of his assertions, but basically, it's all over for the long tail.
When you reference a book and want readers to be able to find more about it, it's common to link to Amazon. There are problems with Amazon being the default site for all books: by linking there you are basically recommending that your readers support Amazon and don't support your local bookstore.
So how about linking to Open Library instead whenever you mention a book, like the best novel ever? It's an evolving initiative with a fine mission: One web page for every book. It's got some quirks still – the treatment of books with many editions is a bit of an issue – but it's a great idea and it's noncommercial, which is hugely important for a common resource. You won't find much information there about most books, but you will find links to buy a book at some of the bigger online bookstores and to your local library catalogue if you're lucky.
Now if only they could link to your local bookshop, which should be possible for those who have online ordering stores like our neighbourhood one, I'd be very happy with it.
Obviously there's more work to be done there, but one way to get it done is to make people aware of it, and one way to do that is to link to it.
So spread the word: link books to their Open Library page.
I have an opinion piece at the world's best and most scurrilous Information Technology rag, The Register. See The Long Fail.
After yesterday's bout, Tim O'Reilly responds to Nicholas Carr and Nicholas Carr responds
to Tim O'Reilly's response. There's something about the blog world that
makes referring to these two as Carr and O'Reilly seem terse, and yet
to call them Nick and Tim just looks unctuous. So I'll call them by
their initials: NC (C for Carr and Cloud) and TO (for Tim O'Reilly and
Two point O).
To bring you up to date:
TO
actually has a point, and I agree with him that NC is overly-narrow.
There are many kinds of indirect network effects that still qualify for the name. For example, here I am
referencing only TO and NC while others have also
contributed to the debate. And I suspect that TO and NC have taken this
issue up because their opponent is an A-list blogger and so a dispute
gives the issue a prominence it would otherwise not have. So both TO and NC are gaining readers because they already have a lot of existing readers. So the world turns.
But on the big issue, I still side with NC. Here's why.
TO defines the original issue as this claim, written by Hugh Macleod:
"Nobody's saying that one day a single company may possibly emerge to
dominate The Cloud, the way Google came to dominate Search, the way
Microsoft came to dominate Software." But then TO later redefines the
question as whether the cloud infrastructure business is likely to be a
low-margin business based on selling commodities. Given NC's question
"will the infrastructure suppliers also come to dominate the supply of
apps?" the dispute is actually about not one question, but a set of distinct questions:
You see, this is why I'm no top blogger. Each of these is a complicated
question, and I'm not qualified to answer any of them. It's not even
clear to me which of these questions are separate. This is why I don't
trust big ideas or catchy names and why I'll never write a best-selling
business book (well, one reason. I'm sure there are many more). But in
pursuit of some light rather than heat I'll try to draw some lines.
Most importantly, the first three of these questions are obviously related, but TO combines them and confusion results. A typical commodity business (selling
widgets that are the same as the next guy's widgets) is low margin
because a commodity business is characterised by decreasing returns and
so by low barriers to entry and intense price competition. But you can
be in the business of selling commodities and yet still profit from
increasing returns. Amazon is a prime example. Books are commodities
(anyone can sell a book), and this limits Amazon's margin per book to
being small. But online bookstores are not commodities – they are
characterised by huge fixed costs (the Amazon computing infrastructure)
and there are massive barriers to entry in the online bookselling
business. So Amazon is a low-margin seller of commodities but is also a
near-monopoly. Wal-Mart is another example in the physical world – it's
obviously in a low margin business (really low) but it has used
economies of scale to build a large market share in the US. Telcos and
utility companies are others where the forces towards a natural
monopoly are strong enough to have attracted antitrust action while
still being low-margin. Few would dispute the fact that Amazon and
Wal-Mart are both immensely powerful companies. The argument that
"infrastructure cloud computing is a commodity business, therefore no single
company will dominate that layer of the cloud" is simply false.
Is infrastructure cloud computing a natural monopoly? There are many
forces (network effects and others) pushing it in that direction, but
there are others (the variety of services demanded in particular) that
pull it away from a natural monopoly. I suspect this market will be
oligopolistic rather than monopolistic – that there will be enough
fragmentation in the kinds of offering available that a demand for
variety will make it more like the automobile industry than like the
online bookstore industry.
Do profits lie solely at the top layer of the cloud? Again, no. You can
be low-margin and high profit as long as the scale is big enough (see
Amazon and Wal-Mart, above).
And finally, are synergies enough that a single company (Google being
the obvious one) may come to dominate all layers of the cloud? That's a
hell of a question. If there is any company that could do so it would be Google. And
if it does then I hope the antitrust people are all over it. But
sources of variety are surprising – many people thought that the age of
TV would mean local accents would die out, but of course they are still strong in many places – and I am hopeful
that there are enough such sources to prevent the web collapsing into a
Google-shaped black hole.
But guess what? Not all Internet industries are monopolies and if we are to get to grips with industry concentration in Internet-driven industries we need to acknowledge that different digital industries are pushed by different forces. Different parts of the cloud computing world really are different and will see different levels of concentration.
What we need to do is not so much look at the sources of increasing returns to scale, which are many, but instead look for what factors might limit increasing returns and prevent the expected monopolies from forming. Any such factor will affect different digital industries in different ways. I'll just look at one factor to show what I mean.
And that's why I am inclined to agree with Carr.
Timothy Lee has an excellent post at Freedom To Tinker. Here is some of it:
[T]alking about "free riding" as a problem the Wikipedia community needs to solve doesn't make any sense. The overwhelming majority of Wikipedia users "free ride," and far from being a drag on Wikipedia's growth, this large audience acts as a powerful motivator for continued contribution to the site. People like to contribute to an encyclopedia with a large readership; indeed, the enormous number of "free-riders"—a.k.a. users—is one of the most appealing things about being a Wikipedia editor.
This is more than a semantic point. Unfortunately, the "free riding" frame is one of the most common ways people discuss the economics of online content creation, and I think it has been an obstacle to clear thinking.
The idea of "free riding" is based on a couple of key 20th-century assumptions that just don't apply to the online world. The first assumption is that the production of content is a net cost that must either be borne by the producer or compensated by consumers. This is obviously true for some categories of content—no one has yet figured out how to peer-produce Hollywood-quality motion pictures, for example—but it's far from universal.
Moreover, the real world abounds in counterexamples. No one loses sleep over the fact that people "free ride" off of watching company softball games, community orchestras, or amateur poetry readings. To the contrary, it's understood that the vast majority of musicians, poets, and athletes find these activities intrinsically enjoyable, and they're grateful to have an audience "free ride" off of their effort.The same principle applies to Wikipedia. Participating in Wikipedia is a net positive experience for both readers and editors. We don't need to "solve" the free rider problem because there are more than enough people out there for whom the act of contributing is its own reward.
You can see how we got into this problem. Britannica is an encyclopedia and it is an economic enterprise. Wikipedia ends in pedia so it must be an economic enterprise too. But it is not, and we should look elsewhere for our analogies. Once we stop thinking of Wikipedia in economic terms the supposed paradox disappears. Small wonder that, as Lee says, economists are the ones who have the hardest time understanding it.